Feed on
Posts
Comments

JB asked in the comments to an earlier post what we know about who bears the burden of cigarette taxation. A brief exploration of the economic literature reveals the following:

(1) The Heterogeneous Geographic and Socioeconomic Incidence of Cigarette Taxes: Evidence from Nielsen Homescan Data
Author: Harding, Matthew; Leibtag, Ephraim; Lovenheim, Michael F.
Author Affiliation: Stanford U; USDA; Cornell U
Source: American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, November 2012, v. 4, iss. 4, pp. 169-98
Publication Date: November 2012
Abstract: We use Nielsen Homescan data to examine who bears the economic burden of cigarette taxes. We find cigarette taxes are less than fully passed through to consumer prices, suggesting consumers and producers split the excess burden of these taxes. Using information on consumer location, we show the availability of lower-tax goods across state borders creates significant differences in the pass-through rate. Tax avoidance opportunities also have a sizable effect on purchasing behavior by altering consumer search, prices paid and quantities purchased. Finally, we demonstrate that the incidence of cigarette taxes and the border effect varies by household income and education.

 

WINTERCOW: here is a link for those who can get access. On p. 192 we find that the poor don’t actually experience as serious an impact of the tax burden as you would think, because although the poor smoke more, they also search more for alternatives (roll your own, out of state purchases, etc.) than wealthier people do. You can see Table 8 in the paper for specific information on how much they actually bear.

 

(2) Consumer Response to Cigarette Excise Tax Changes
Author: Chiou, Lesley; Muehlegger, Eric
Author Affiliation: Occidental College; Harvard University
Publisher Information: Harvard University, John F. Kennedy School of Government, Working Paper Series
Publication Date: 2010
Abstract: We use a rich dataset of weekly cigarette sales to examine how consumers adapt their behavior before and after excise taxincreases–whether by reducing demand, stockpiling, traveling to low-tax jurisdictions, or substituting towards lower-cost brands. Consumer response varies substantially for different types of cigarettes. Stockpiling primarily occurs for discount cigarettes and is most pronounced at stores far from lower-tax jurisdictions. Border-crossing is greatest at stores close to low-tax jurisdictions and occurs primarily for cigarettessold by the carton. Finally, we find modest short-run substitution towards lower-cost brands following a tax-increase, consistent with consumers smoothing the transition to higher cigarette taxes. These differences in consumer behavior lead to meaningful differences intax incidence–pass-through is higher for discount cigarettes which have more inelastic demand. Pass-through is lower near low-taxborders, especially for cigarettes sold by the carton for which cross-border evasion is greatest.

 

WINTERCOW: here is a copy of the paper. Table 4 has some relevant data. It does not appear that stockpiling behavior varies by income class.

 

(3) Who Pays Cigarette Taxes? The Impact of Consumer Price Search
Author: DeCicca, Philip; Kenkel, Donald S.; Liu, Feng
Author Affiliation: Unlisted; Unlisted; Unlisted
Publisher Information: National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc, NBER Working Papers: 15942
Publication Date: 2010
Abstract: We conduct an empirical study of the impact of consumer price-search on the shifting of cigarette excise taxes to consumer prices. We use novel data on the prices smokers report actually paying for cigarettes. We document substantial price dispersion. We find that cigarette taxes are shifted at lower rates to the prices paid by consumers who undertake more price search–carton buyers, and especially, smokers who buy cartons of cigarettes in a state other than their state of residence. We also find suggestive evidence thattaxes are shifted at slightly higher rates to the prices paid by non-daily smokers, less addicted smokers, and smokers of light cigarettes.
Publication Type: Working Paper
Availability: http://www.nber.org.ezp.lib.rochester.edu/papers/w15942.pdf

 

WINTERCOW: It appears that we don’t have a lot of direct research on just how much of the burden is passed on to the poor. Here is a key extract from the end of the paper: ”

Another direction for future work is to explore the implications of price search
for the incidence of cigarette taxes across income groups. Standard analyses conclude
that because smokers have lower incomes in the U.S., cigarette taxes are regressive
(Lyon and Schwab 1995, Colman and Remler 2008). These standard analyses are
incomplete if taxes are differentially passed through to the prices paid by consumers
with different incomes. Indeed, Heiding, Leibtag and Lovenheim (2010) find that
cigarette taxes are fully shifted to the prices middle-income consumers pay, but less
than fully shifted to the prices paid by both low- and high-income consumers. Future
work could further explore the role of consumer price search in these patterns of tax
incidence and income.

 

 

(4) Tax Incidence When Individuals Are Time-Inconsistent: The Case of Cigarette Excise Taxes
Author: Gruber, Jonathan; Koszegi, Botond
Author Affiliation: MIT; U CA, Berkeley
Source: Journal of Public Economics, August 2004, v. 88, iss. 9-10, pp. 1959-87
Publication Date: August 2004
Abstract: One of the most cogent criticisms of excise taxes is their regressivity, with lower income groups spending a much larger share of their income on goods such as cigarettes than do higher income groups. We argue that traditional quantity-based measures of incidenceare only appropriate under a very restrictive “time-consistent” model of consumption of sin goods. A model that is much more consistent with existing evidence on smoking decisions is a time-inconsistent formulation where excise taxes on cigarettes serve a self-control function that is valued by smokers who would like to quit but cannot. This self-control function benefits lower income groups more, since they have a significantly higher price sensitivity of smoking. Calibrations show that, as a result, cigarette taxes are much less regressive than previously assumed, and are even progressive for a wide variety of parameter values.

 

WINTERCOW: So we have suggestions that cigarette taxes are possibly progessive. One important reason for this is that lower income consumers are much more sensitive to price changes than higher income ones and it is not just in search for lower priced cigarettes but also their propensity to quit.

 

 

(5) Consumption Taxes in a Life-Cycle Framework: Are Sin Taxes Regressive?
Author: Lyon, Andrew B.; Schwab, Robert M.
Author Affiliation: U MD; U MD
Source: Review of Economics and Statistics, August 1995, v. 77, iss. 3, pp. 389-406
Publication Date: August 1995
Abstract: We construct measures of tax incidence over the life-cycle and compare these measures to traditional measures based on annual data. Annual measures of the incidence of taxes on consumption goods may differ from life-cycle measures for three reasons. First, annual measures of income reflect transitory components which should have smaller effects on consumption than permanent changes in income. Second, income measured in a single period differs from lifetime income due to age-related differences in earnings. Third, consumption of certain items follows life-cycle patterns independent of changes in income. Surprisingly, we find that these effects cause little change in the assessment of the incidence of taxes on cigarettes. For alcohol, we find that a tax on its consumption is slightly less regressive when measured with respect to lifetime income than when measured with respect to annual income.
ISSN: 00346535
Publication Type: Journal Article

 

WINTERCOW: On p. 398 and 399 of the paper you will find their evidence that cigarette taxes, over the 1968-72 period, appear to be regressive.

 

 

There are a few other scattered papers that tangentially address the question. But I would say based on the limited evidence that the jury is out on the actual incidence.

5 Responses to “Cigarette Tax Incidence”

  1. Harry says:

    Wow! Ask a good question, jb, and you might get some help.

    Regarding cigarettes, and the butts, and Coase, why should I or my yard guy not be salaried by the federal government to pick up the many butts and cigarette trash (many menthol brands, Newport, Marlboro menthol, even Virginia Slims menthol) that people throw along the road? Surely this is a problem that should be solved by government using some of Wintercow’s and Coyote’s money. Steve Landsburg’s money. He is awash in money, we assume, with enough to pay for a gardener for all three of us, plus governor Cuomo’s Mexican gardener.

  2. Harry says:

    Moreover, I am overwhelmed by WC, this fountain of facts and ideas, jb.

    Straight cigarettes used to cost 25 cents a pack in the machine in my college dorm, about the same as a gallon of gas. It took about nine gallons of gas to do a road trip to Vassar. How much would it cost to go to Vassar, per person, assuming they consumed seven Marlboros, and drank 5/6 of a six pack, the designated driver doing two beers each way, and being reimbursed fully by the passengers for the use of the car plus the gas and his beers? Four passengers.

    I would like to see how fast it would take Ben Bernanke to solve that word problem, and then to predict what it would cost for the road trip per person in 2015, assuming the Fed continues to buy ten-year Treasurys at the current pace.

  3. Michael says:

    On a couple of links, I would mention that although rolling your own and going out of the way to puchase out of state (Missouri) cigarettes doesn’t necessarily mean extra expenditure, it does possibly place an additional cost on the poor. Rolling you own takes a bit of time and out of state probably requires planning out the purchases more than just deciding to run to the corner market. (I’m more familiar with the former than the latter, though I don’t smoke.)

  4. Harry says:

    Of course if you are a connected New Yorker, you buy bootleg cartons off the back of a trailer. If you are really connected, you can do one-stop shopping for a Glock and other things to smoke and ingest. Buy local. Don’t try this on Center Street.

  5. jb says:

    Wow ask and I shall receive…thanks so much WC, truly a trove of research to look over here. If you come to the Berkshires and don’t let me know, you’ll have yourself to blame because the offer to buy you a beer has increased to at least 2 beers.

    Hmmm let’s see. Let me make a very simplisitic generalization that these studies on the whole suggest that “smoking is not necessarily regressive”. So let’s assume that’s the case. That means that the poor do not quit smoking in proportion to the wealthy when these taxes are imposed. But cigarette taxes are touted as a way to get people to quit, for their own good. If that is the intent, then cigarette taxes appear to be helping upper income classes, but not the poor, right?

Leave a Reply to Harry